There are proponents and opponents of centralising the regulation of the financial system, with some arguing that it should be managed by Central Banks.
Regardless of your stance on the matter, the crux of the debate lies not in whether centralisation of regulation should occur, but rather when and how central banks should assume these responsibilities.
During the 2008 financial market crisis, swift and decisive action was required from many regulators, including central banks. Their role was to stabilise the financial system and prevent the collapse of banks and other systemic financial institutions. However, the coordination of the efforts of various regulators, particularly central banks, who were not the main regulatory bodies in many jurisdictions, was lacking.
Regulators responsible for different market segments struggled to coordinate their efforts, sometimes acting unilaterally against each other. This highlighted the need for swift, coordinated action from regulators when institutions and financial markets collapse. Central Banks are ideally positioned to assume this role of central command and control.
From the start of the crisis, regulators were caught off guard by the inter-connectivity between banks and financial institutions. While they believed globalisation of financial markets had occurred, they lacked understanding of the interconnectedness between market players like banks and non-bank financial institutions. This lack of awareness led to a perception that matters could spiral out of control rapidly due to this inter-connectivity.
Operating in a globally inter-connected market raises issues around the concept of lender-of-last-resort. In particular, which regulator in what regulatory jurisdiction should take on the final regulatory responsibility for intervention to save institutions when the financial system fails, whether they be banks or non-banks.
Consider that a regulator solely responsible for the efficient operation of banks may not fully comprehend or consider how their decision to save specific banks from failure could impact other areas of the financial system. Accounting for the interconnectedness of the financial system, a failure could originate from any point and be caused by the actions of various players, including banks, insurance firms, and asset managers. In each case, these players are often regulated by different regulators, with central banks playing a limited role in day-to-day regulation.
During the financial market crisis of 2008, it is clear that the State in various jurisdictions took responsibility for stabilising failure in their own financial system. But, while they may fulfil the lender-of-last-resort role, they are often not the actual market regulator.
In extreme market stress conditions, the State will normally take on the role of lender-of-last-resort. It is never some arbitrarily independent regulatory body like the FSA (abolished in 2013) in the United Kingdom or APRA in Australia who fills this role. Independent regulatory bodies simply do not have the financial resources available compared to Central Banks.
As the banker to the State, Central Banks have access to resources that independent regulatory bodies do not. Independent regulators must, in circumstances of market failure, approach Central Banks directly anyway for help because they control these financial resources as the bankers to the State and not the independent regulator.
The inherent problem in existing arrangements is the delay in response to market failures. This is because Central Banks, being detached from the day-to-day supervision of markets by independent regulators, often need to be convinced of the necessity to intervene before they can take action. This process of persuasion can lead to further delays, potentially exacerbating the problem. The image of the Roman Emperor Nero playing his fiddle while Rome burns serves as a poignant reminder of the consequences of inaction.
It follows that because it is the State that ultimately carries accountability for stemming failure in the financial system, that it must be their banker or Central Banks that carry out the duty of lender-of-last-resort on behalf of the State.
Due to this duty, it is clearly necessary for Central Banks to stay close to all activities conducted in the financial system. Therefore, there is a strong case for Central Banks to be involved and regulate key financial market activity. Central banks are also ideally positioned to serve as a coordination point for regulating the diverse modern financial market.
Policy setters are aware of the relationship between the State, Central Banks, and the financial market. They will undoubtedly consider this relationship when establishing any regulatory system following the 2008 financial market crisis.